The consumption
function is based on the assumption that there is a constant relationship
between consumption and income, as denoted by constant b which is marginal
propensity to consume. The concept of MPC describes the relationship between
change in consumption (∆C) and the change in income (∆Y). The value of the
increment to consumer expenditure per unit of increment to income is termed the
Marginal Propensity to Consume (MPC). Although the MPC is not necessarily constant for all changes
in income (in fact, the MPC tends to decline at higher
income levels), most analysis of consumption generally works with a constant
MPC.
Average Propensity to Consume (APC)
Just as marginal
propensity to consume, the average propensity to consume is a ratio of
consumption defining income consumption relationship. The ratio of total
consumption to total income is known as the average propensity to
consume (APC).
APC = Total
consumption/total income = CC/YY (2.6)
The table below shows the
relationship between income consumption and saving.
Relationship between Income and
Consumption
Income (Y)
|
Consumption (C )
|
APC ( C/Y)
|
MPC(∆C /∆Y)
|
MPS(∆S
(1-MPC)
|
0
|
500
|
500/0 = ∞
|
-
|
-
|
1000
|
1250
|
1250/1000 = 1.25
|
750/1000 = 0.75
|
0.25
|
2000
|
2000
|
2000/2000 = 1.00
|
750/1000 = 0.75
|
0.25
|
3000
|
2750
|
2750/3000 = 0.92
|
750/1000 = 0.75
|
0.25
|
6000
|
5000
|
5000/6000 = 0.83
|
1500/2000 = 0.75
|
0.25
|
10,000
|
8000
|
8000/10,000 = 0.80
|
3000/4000 = 0.75
|
0.25
|
APC is calculated at various income
levels. It is obvious that the proportion
of income spent on consumption decreases as income increases. What happens
to the rest of the income that is not spent on consumption? If it is not spent,
it must be saved because income is either spent or saved; there are no other used
to which it can be put. Thus, just as consumption, saving is a function of income.
S=f(Y).
The Saving Function
In figure 1.2.3, the consumption and
saving functions are graphed. The saving function shows the level of saving (S)
at each level of disposable income (Y). The intercept for the saving function, (—a)
is the (negative) level of saving at
zero level of disposable income at consumption equal to ‘a’ . By definition, national
income Y
= C + S which shows that disposable
income is, by definition, consumption plus saving. Therefore, S = Y – C. Thus,
when we represent the theory of the consumption-income relationship, it also
implicitly establishes the saving-income relationship.
The Marginal Propensity to Save (MPS)
The slope of the saving function is the
marginal propensity to save. If a one-unit increase in disposable income leads
to an increase of b units in consumption, the remainder (1 - b) is the increase
in saving. This increment to saving per unit increase in disposable income (1 -
b) is called the marginal propensity to save (MPS). In other words, the marginal propensity to save
is the increase in saving per unit increase in disposable income.
Marginal Propensity to Consume (MPC) is always less than unity, but
greater than zero, i.e., 0 < b < 1 Also, MPC + MPS = 1; we have MPS 0
< b < 1. Thus, saving is an
increasing function of the level of income because the marginal propensity to
save (MPS) = 1- b is positive, i.e. saving increase as income increases.
Average Propensity to Save (APS)
The ratio of total saving to total income is
called average propensity to save (APS). Alternatively, it is that part of
total income which is saved.
APS = Total saving/ Total income = SS/YY
(2.8)
In figure 2.3 showing the consumption and
saving functions, the 45° line is drawn
to split the positive quadrant of the
graph and shows the income-consumption relation with Y = C (AD = Y) at all
levels of income. All points on the 45° line indicate that aggregate
expenditure equal aggregate output; i.e. the value of the variables measured on
the vertical axis (C+I) is equal to the value of the variable measured on the horizontal axis ( i.e. Y). Because
aggregate expenditures equal total output
for all points along the 45-degree line, the line maps out all possible equilibrium
income levels. As long as the economy is operating at less than its full-employment
capacity, producers will produce any output along the 45-degree line that they believe
purchasers will buy.
THE TWO-SECTOR MODEL OF NATIONAL INCOME DETERMINATION
In this section, we shall describe
the two-sector model of determination of equilibrium levels of output and
income in its formal form using the aggregate demand function and the aggregate
supply function. According to Keynesian
theory of income determination, the equilibrium level of national income is a situation
in which aggregate demand (C+ I) is equal to aggregate supply (C + S) i.e.,
C
+ I = C + S
Or
I
= S (2.9)
In a two sector economy, the
aggregate demand (C+ I) refers to the total spending
in the economy i.e. it is the sum
of demand for the consumer goods (C) and investment goods (I) by households and
firms respectively. In figure 1.2.4, the aggregate demand curve is linear and
positively sloped indicating that as the level
of national income rises, the aggregate demand (or aggregate spending)
in the economy also rises. The aggregate expenditure line is flatter than
the 45-degree line because, as income
rises, consumption also increases, but by less than the increase in income.
Figure 1.2.4
Determination of Equilibrium Income: Two Sector Model
You may bear in mind the basic
point that according to Keynes, aggregate demand will not always be equal to
aggregate supply. Aggregate demand depends on households plan to consume and to
save. Aggregate supply depends on the producers’ plan to produce goods and
services. For the aggregate demand and the aggregate supply to be equal so that
equilibrium is established, the households’ plan must coincide with producers’
plan. The expectations of businessmen are realized only when aggregate expenditure
equals aggregate income. In other words,
aggregate supply represents aggregate value expected by business firms and aggregate demand represents their
realized value. At equilibrium, expected value equals realized value. However,
Keynes held the view that that there is no reason to believe that:
i. consumers’ consumption plan always coincides with producers’
production plan, and
ii. that producers’ plan to invest matches always with households
plan to save
Putting it differently, there is no
reason for C + I and C + S to be always equal.
The figure 1.2.4 depicts the determination
of equilibrium income. Income is measured along the horizontal axis and the
components of aggregate demand, C and I, are measured along the vertical axis. The
consumption function (I) is shown in panel B of the figure, the (C+ I) or
aggregate expenditure schedule which is obtained by adding the autonomous
expenditure component namely investment to consumption spending at each
level of income. Since the autonomous expenditure component (I) does not depend
directly on income, the (C+I) schedule lies above the consumption function by a
constant amount. Equilibrium level of income is such that aggregate demand equals
output (which in turn equals income). Only
at point E and at the corresponding equilibrium levels of income and output (Y0),
does aggregate demand exactly equal output. At that level of output and income,
planned spending precisely matches production.
Once national income is determined,
it will remain stable in the short run.
Our understanding of the equilibrium
level of income would be better if we find out why the other points on the graph are not
points of equilibrium. For example, consider a level of income below Y0, for
example Y1, generates consumption as shown along the consumption function. When
this level of consumption is added to the autonomous investment expenditure (I),
the aggregate demand exceeds income; i.e the (C +1) schedule is above the 45°
line. Equivalently, at all those levels I is greater than S, as can be seen in
panel (B) of the figure 1.2.4. The aggregate expenditures exceed aggregate
output. Excess demand makes businesses to sell more than what they currently
produce. The unexpected sales would draw down inventories and result in less
inventory investment than business firms planned. They will react by hiring more
workers and expanding production. This will increase the nation’s aggregate
income. It also follows that with demand outstripping production, desired investment
will exceed actual investment.
Conversely, at levels of income above
Y0, for example at Y2, output exceed demand (the 45° line is above the C +I schedule).
The planned expenditures on goods and services are less than what business
firms thought they would be; business firms would be unable to sell as much of
their current output as they had expected. In
fact, they have unintentionally made larger inventory investments than
they planned and their actual
inventories would increase. Therefore, there will be a tendency for output to fall.
This process continues till output reaches Y0, at which current production exactly
matches planned aggregate spending and unintended inventory shortfall or
accumulation are therefore equal to zero. At this point, consumers’ plan
matches with producers’ plan and savers’ plan matches with investors’ plan. Consequently,
there is no tendency for output to change.
Since C + S = Y, the national
income equilibrium can be written as
Y
= C + I (2.10)
The saving schedule S slopes upward
because saving varies positively with income.
In equilibrium, planned investment
equals saving. Therefore, corresponding to this income, the saving schedule (S)
intersects the horizontal investment schedule (I). This intersection is shown in panel (B) of figure
1.2.4.
This condition applies only to an economy
in which there is no government and no foreign trade. To understand this relationship,
refer to panel (B) of figure 1.2.4 Without government and foreign trade, the vertical
distance between the aggregate demand (C+I) and consumption line
(C) in the figure is equal to planned investment spending, I. You may also find
that the vertical distance between the consumption schedule and the 45° line
also measures saving (S = Y- C) at each level of income. At the equilibrium level of income (at point E
in panel B), and only at that level, the
two vertical distances are equal. Thus, at the equilibrium level of income, saving
equals (planned) investment. By contrast, above
the equilibrium level of income, Y0
, saving (the distance between 45° line and the consumption schedule) exceeds planned
investment, while below Y0 level of income, planned investment exceeds saving.
The equality between saving and
investment can be seen directly from the identities in national income
accounting. Since income is either spent or saved, Y = C + S. Without
government and foreign trade, aggregate demand equals consumption plus
investment, Y = C + I. Putting the two together, we have C + S = C + I, or S =
I.
An important point to remember is
that Keynesian equilibrium with equality of planned aggregate expenditures and output
need not take place at full employment.
It is possible that the rate of unemployment is high. In the Keynesian model, neither
wages nor interest rates will decline in the face of abnormally high unemployment
and excess capacity. Therefore, output will remain at less than the full employment
rate as long as there is insufficient spending in the economy. Keynes argued that
this was precisely what was happening during the Great Depression.
THE INVESTMENT MULTIPLIER
In our two-sector model, a change
in aggregate demand may be caused by change in consumption expenditure or in
business investment or in both. Since Consumption expenditure is a stable function
of income, changes in income are primarily from changes in the autonomous components
of aggregate demand, especially from changes in the unstable investment component.
We shall now examine the effect of an increase in investment (upward shift in
the investment schedule) causing an upward shift in the aggregate demand function.
Figure 1.2.5
Effect of Changes in Autonomous Investment
In the figure 1.2.5, an increase in
autonomous investment by ∆ I shifts the aggregate demand schedule from C+I to
C+I+ ∆I. Correspondingly, the equilibrium shifts from E to E1 and the
equilibrium income increases more than proportionately from Yo to Y1. Why and how does this happen? This
occurs due to the operation of the investment multiplier.
The multiplier refers to the
phenomenon whereby a change in an injection of expenditure will lead to a
proportionately larger change (or multiple change) in the level of national
income. Multiplier explains how many times the aggregate income increases as a
result of an increase in investment. When the level of investment increases by
an amount say ∆I, the equilibrium level of income will increase by some
multiple amounts, ∆ Y. The ratio of ∆Y to ∆I is called the investment
multiplier, k.
K
= ∆Y/∆I (2.11)
The size of the multiplier effect is given by ∆ Y = k ∆I.
For
example, if a change in investment of ` 2000 million causes a
change in national income of ` 6000 million, then the multiplier is 6000/2000 =3.
Thus multiplier indicates the change in national income for each rupee change
in the desired investment. The value 3 in the above example tells us that for
every ` 1 increase in desired investment expenditure, there will be ` 3
increase in equilibrium national income. Multiplier, therefore, expresses the relationship
between an initial increment in investment
and the resulting increase in aggregate income. Since the increase in national income
(∆Y) is the result of increase in investment (∆I), the multiplier is called ‘investment
multiplier.’
The process behind the multiplier can
be compared to the ‘ripple effect’ of
water. Let us assume that the initial disturbance comes from a change in
autonomous investment (∆I) of 500 units. The economy being in equilibrium, an
upward shift in aggregate demand leads to an increase in national income which
in a two sector economy will be, by definition, distributed as factor incomes.
There will be an equal increase in disposable income. Firms experience increased
demand and as a response, their output increases. Assuming that MPC is 0.80,
consumption expenditure increases by 400, resulting in increase in production.
The process does not stop here; it will generate a second-round of increase in
income. The process further continues as an
autonomous rise in investment leads to induced increases in consumer demand as income increases we find
that the marginal propensity to
consume (MPC) is the
determinant of the value of the multiplier
and that there exists a direct relationship between MPC and the value of
multiplier. Higher the MPC, more
will be the value of the multiplier, and vice-versa. On the contrary, higher
the MPS, lower will be the value of multiplier and vice-versa. The maximum
value of multiplier is infinity when the value of MPC is 1 i.e the economy
decides to consume the whole of its additional
income. We conclude that the value of the multiplier is the reciprocal of MPS.
For example, if the value of MPC is
0.75, then the value of the multiplier is multiplier as per (2. 11) is:
1/0.25 = 4
The multiplier concept is central to Keynes's theory because it explains how shifts in investment caused by
changes in business expectations set off a process that causes not only
investment but also consumption to vary. The multiplier shows how shocks to one
sector are transmitted throughout the economy.
Increase in income due to increase
in initial investment, does not go on endlessly. The process of income propagation
slows down and ultimately comes to a halt. Causes responsible for the decline
in income are called leakages. Income that is not spent on currently produced consumption
goods and services may be regarded as having leaked out of income stream. If
the increased income goes out of the cycle
of consumption expenditure, there is a leakage from income stream which
reduces the effect of multiplier. The more powerful these leakages are the smaller
will be
the value of multiplier. The leakages are caused due to:
a) progressive
rates of taxation which result in no appreciable increase in consumption despite
increase in income
b) high
liquidity preference and idle saving or holding of cash balances and an
equivalent fall in marginal propensity to consume
c) increased
demand for consumer goods being met out of the existing stocks or through imports
d) additional
income spent on purchasing existing wealth or purchase of government securities
and shares from shareholders or bond holders
e) undistributed
profits of corporations
f) part
of increment in income used for payment of debts
g) case
of full employment additional investment will only lead to inflation, and
h) scarcity
of goods and services despite having high MPC
The MPC on which the multiplier effect
of increase in income depends, is high in under developed countries; ironically
the value of multiplier is low. Due to structural inadequacies, increase in
consumption expenditure is not generally accompanied by increase in production. E.g. increased
demand for industrial goods consequent
on increased income does not lead to increase in their real output; rather prices tend to rise.
An important element of Keynesian models
is that they relate to short-period equilibrium and contain no dynamic
elements. There is nothing like Keynesian macro-economic dynamics. When a shock
occurs, for example when there is a change in autonomous investment due to
change in some variable, one equilibrium position can be compared with another
as a matter of comparative statics. There is no link between one period and the
next and no provision is made for an
analysis of processes through time.
No comments:
Post a Comment